Lessons About Our Roller-Coaster Stockmarket, from a Highly Unlikely Source


✑ DANTE DALLAVALLE | 1,219 words
‟What Minsky lacks in class analysis, Marx and his predecessors more than make up for.

To fully understand financial cycles, look at both Hyman Minsky's analysis of investors' herd-like behavior, but also Karl Marx to understand why investors fear even the most meager increases in wages over the past year.


Originally published by Alternet (Feb. 16, 2018). 
About the author (click)
Dante Dallavalle is a d@w contributor and cohost of the podcast Left Out. He's a graduate student in economics at John Jay College of Criminal Justice. Follow him on Twitter @Drax138.


"The Wall Streets of this world are important; they generate destabilizing forces, and from time to time the financial processes of our economy lead to serious threats of financial and economic instability, that is, the behavior of the economy becomes incoherent.”

— Hyman Minsky, Stabilizing an Unstable Economy


Published in 1986, the once obscure economist Hyman Minsky would become relevant, indeed revered, by those trying to make sense of what exactly happened after the 2007-'08 financial crisis. Minsky’s financial instability hypothesis is elegant in its dual simplicity and insightfulness. Simply put, stability is destabilizing. Minsky’s theory strays from traditional, or neoclassical theories in that it actually takes money and finance into account when looking at economic phenomena (yes, that’s right, conventional economists don’t think money and finance play a significant role in deriving their models), and that he also situates the economy within an institutional and historical timeframe, something most abstract models disregard.

His thesis goes something like this. After a period of economic crisis, lenders are reluctant to make risky loans, with the recent memory of economic turmoil still fresh in their minds. Making only sound and measured loans whose interest and principal is being repaid, they rest easy at night knowing they’re engaged in relatively risk-free activity. This form of lending is referred to by Minsky as "hedge finance" (distinct from the investment vehicles called hedge funds). As things begin moving along nicely, their eagerness for making more speculative investments begins to rise, engaging in loans whose interest can be repaid, but whose principal must be rolled over at regular intervals. Appropriately, Minsky referred to this type of lending as “speculative finance.”

You can probably see where this is going but I’ll finish his hypothesis. Now with investment rising and stocks increasing in value as a result, everybody (i.e., in the investor class) is happy, perhaps ecstatic. Loans begin to be made to everyone and anyone, regardless of their ability to pay back even interest. The interest gets capitalized, that is it is added to the principal and these loans become ever more unsustainable. These are the riskiest of all the types of lending, and Minsky called this type “Ponzi finance,” after the (not so) infamous Italian immigrant Charles Ponzi, known for his investment schemes of promising 100% returns to his clients after just three months. What Ponzi didn’t reveal was that he would repay older clients with new clients’ money. (He went on to die broke and physically debilitated in a charity hospital in Brazil.)

Karl Marx (left), Hyman Minsky (right) and the 'Stylized Minsky Cycle' (Wikimedia Commons)

The logic behind Minsky’s argument about the financial sector and economic crises is discerning. The recent volatility in the stock market has every pundit and analyst guessing as to why, last week, the markets officially entered into a correction; that is, they dropped by 10% from their peak in late January. Although equities have indeed been rising since the election of Donald Trump, they were already on the rise for nearly nine years since the "official" end of the Great Recession in June 2009. And although markets seem to be rebounding, Minsky’s analysis, laden with concepts such as herd behavior and fallacies of composition, can still teach us a lot about why certain rapid fluctuations occur. It does not, however, tell us about the class dynamics at play. But what Minsky lacks in class analysis, Marx and his predecessors more than make up for.

Related: Economist Doug Henwood on the stock market volatility: "About that Stock Panic" (February 8, 2018)

The standard explanation going around as to why stocks began a precipitous decline has to do with the Federal Reserve. Investors are fearing that an impending rise in interest rates due to inflation fears will cut into corporations’ ability to borrow, eat into profits, and as a consequence devalue their stocks. At the same time, as interest rates rise, bond yields follow suit, making them more attractive and thus encouraging a shift for investors from equities to debt. On the flip side of the coin, as stock prices fall, retirement accounts invested in them fall and people begin spending less. This confluence of factors leads to a weaker economy. For those investors "buying on margin," or borrowing money to purchase stocks, this scenario is the worst of all possible worlds.

So where does class come into all of this? Well, to start, as Patricia Cohen noted in a New York Times article published February 8, “A whopping 84 percent of all stocks owned by Americans belong to the wealthiest 10 percent of households.” This includes everyone with pensions, 401(k)s and IRAs, trust funds, mutual funds, and college saving programs. But while the average working person may not be personally affected directly by mood swings at the stock exchanges, they may have a lot more to do with why the sudden change of heart occurred in the first place.

As unemployment rates stay low (4.1% for the fourth consecutive month), hourly earnings are reported to have risen by 2.9% in January from a year earlier. All of this sounds like good news. In fact, it sounds like what gets politicians elected, with promises and rhetoric of economic security and upward mobility for all. So what’s the problem? The answer to this question essentially gets at the heart of the inherent class antagonisms built into the system. As unemployment falls, it becomes more difficult for employers to find workers. To attract them, they offer higher wages, greater benefits, etc. Competition between employers bids up the price of labor. Workers exercise their newly gained bargaining power. With all things held equal, profits begin to fall. To compensate for this, they attempt to pass the rise in the price of labor onto the consumer by charging higher prices for their final goods/services. And voilà, inflation.
‟Contrary to the politically charged notion of a "free market," unencumbered by the big, bad government, state intervention is crucial for the realization and maintenance of profits of the private sector. 
This is the Marxian notion of the "rising strength of labor variant" in the decline of the rate of profit and is used to explain the formation of crises. James Crotty and Raford Boddy, in their 1975 article “Class Conflict and Macro-Policy: The Political Business Cycle” explain that the state’s role becomes clear in such times: intervene on behalf of employers. To curb inflation, the Fed raises interest rates, making borrowing and investing harder, leading businesses to lay off workers, and hopefully, pushing down the specter of inflation. While this may seem illogical in that it harms some businesses’ bottom-lines in the short-term, the goal is to increase the profitability (power) of the wider private economy (capitalists) in the long-run.

Contrary to the politically charged notion of a "free market," unencumbered by the big, bad government, state intervention is crucial for the realization and maintenance of profits of the private sector. And in many more ways than just the Fed’s role for borrowing. But the point I’m trying to make is this: besides just the "natural" volatility of the stock market already, due to what Minsky conceived of as "destabilizing stability," the notion of class conflict is not only theoretical, but observable in investor’s fear of a meager increase in wages over the past year. Compare that to stagnating (and in some estimates declining) wages we’ve experienced for the average worker since the '70s, and the true nature of the system we live and work in every day comes into biting relief.

If you aren’t an investor in stocks, you may be largely unconcerned about the news this week. But if you are just a mere worker in this big game of capital, and you’re thinking of asking for a raise sometime soon, have a little decency and think about all those poor, wealthy speculators on Wall Street who may just suffer at the hands of your request.



Paul Sliker contributed to this article during editing.

Comments





Stay Updated


to SE's weekly
e-mail update


    








Also Read










Topics


 
more current affairs


more unequal world


more big banks


more economics (the science)


more ideals


more marx


more 1917-1989












Exploring alternatives.

Is SE "socialist"? SE is not anything, except
convinced of the need for a fundamental, global,
open debate about capitalism and possible fair,
egalitarian, democratic and greener alternatives,
from an economic perspective.

Read more about SE here.





Contributors




Avatar
Ghosh
Avatar
Milanovic
Avatar
Henwood
Avatar
Patnaik
Avatar
Hahnel
Avatar
Shaikh
Avatar
Hudson
Avatar
Kliman
Avatar
Ruccio
Avatar
Samary
Avatar
Patnaik
Avatar
Huber
Avatar
Zaman
Avatar
Rasmus
Avatar
Bockman
Avatar
Norfield







SE welcomes your submissions.

Your analyses of past or present economic issues.

Your visions for a better economic future.

See how to submit here.








SE is a platform, open to a diversity of views from thinkers from across the globe.
Views expressed in articles on SE do not necessarily reflect the views of SE's editors.